Tranholm-Mikkelsen, Jeppe, 1991. "Neo-functionalism: Obstinate or Obsolete? A Reappraisal in the Light of the New Dynamism of the EC", _Millenium: Journal of International Studies_. Vol 20, No 1, pp 4-6 (of 1-21). ----- An excerpt ----- *The Logic of Spill-Over* The central thesis of neo-functionalism is that integration within one sector will tend to beget its own impetus and spread to other sectors. The establishment of supranational institutions designed to deal with functionally specific tasks will set in motion economic, social and political processes which generate pressures towards further integration. This is the logic subsumed under the headings of 'spill-over' or 'the expansive logic of sector integration'.16 There are three aspects of this snowball effect: functional spill-over, political spill-over and cultivated spill-over." (a) *Functional Spill-Over.* This is a mechanism arising from the inherent technical characteristics of the functional tasks themselves. The idea is that some sectors within industrial economics are so interdependenlt that it is impossible to treat them in isolatiom. Hence, attempts to integrate certain functional tasks will inevitably lead to problems which can only be solved by integrating yet more tasks.18 This was the type of spill-over envisaged by Jean Monnet. To him, it seemed obvious that the integration of basic industries, such as coal and steel must evenltually lead to a need for integration first of other energy sectors and later of the whole economy.19 It is important to note, however, that this conception of integration was firmly bound up with the idea of *dirigisme* (i.e., indicative planning in order to further industrial modernisation). In Monnet's view, the High Authority should engage in such intervention modelled on the practice of the French *Commisariat du Plan*, of which he was the head.20 Lindberg, on the other hand, emphasised the inherently expansive nature of the tasks assigned to the EEC. In the EEC treaty, the integrative potential was identified not in indicative planning, but in the attempts to create 'a real customs union'. The merging of six economies, he argued, 'will require action transcending the borders of any one state', hence making it difficult for the new institutions to avoid making 'centralising policies'.21 He thus foresaw spill-over from what came to be known as 'negative integration' (i.e., the removal or discrimination between economic agents of the member states) to 'positive integration' (i.e., the adoption of coordinated and common policies).22 (b) *Political Spill-Over.* This mechanism arises from the pluralist nature of Wesl European societies. In such societies, it was argued, politics is based on conflict between groups, each of which pursue their own (welfare) aims.23 Moreover, these groups are represented by highly bureaucratised organisations, thus making it possible to confine the analytical focus to their leaders - the 'elites'.24 This conception of politics owes much to the early 'group theorists' of American political science.25 The idea is that such elites will undergo a learning process, developing the perception that their interests are better served by seeking supranational rather than national solutions. They will therefore refocus their activities, expectations and perhaps their loyalties to the new centre. Such reorientation will lead to calls for further integration, hence providing the process with political impetus. Lindberg, in particular, stressed the importance of governmental elites in this connection. He noted that the EEC had led to a vast and complex bureaucratic system, involving thousands of national and Community officials in a continuous decision-making process. This was due to the establishment of the Committee of Permanent Representatives (COREPER) and of a tremendous number of sub-committees and study groups. Thus, a system of 'bureaucratic interpenetration' had developed in which governments found it increasingly difficult to function as gate-keepers. National officials would 'just pick up the phone' rather than use the formal channels. Moreover, the involvement of these officials would tens to 'engage' them personally in the process, perhaps even leading to 'informal co-optation'.26 This is the process which has later come to be known as *engrenage*.27 Haas, on the other hand, dealt almost exclusively with non-governmental elites. His focus was on the behaviour and perceptions of leaders of political parties, trade associations and trade unions. He identified the changes happening at the national level as well as the establishment of umbrella organisations at the supranational level. To him, the 'chief finding' was that such groups will generate pressures which 'will spill over into the federal sphere and thereby add to the integrative impulse'.28 (c) *Cultivated Spill-Over.* Although the processes outlined above in themselves provide strong pressures towards further integration, both Haas and Lindberg placed much emphasis on the role of central institutions, especially the Commission.29 Such institutions were to embody the common interest and hence function as midwives for the integration process. This idea was elaborated by Haas in an article published in 1961. He argued that classical diplomatic negotiations rarely move beyond the 'minimum common denominator'. In such settings the outcome will be determined by the position of the least co-operative partner. If mediatory services are provided, however, negosiations may move somewhat further and involve 'splitting the difference'. This entails a solution which lies somewhere between the final bargaining positions of the parties. Finally, where accommodation can be facilitated by an autonomous and institutionalised mediator, such as the Commission, the result may be based on 'upgrading of the common interest'. In this case, the outcome involves a redefining of the conflict and almost invariably implies the expansion of the powers of an international agency.30 The prime role of the Commission, therefore, is to offer solutions which involve an 'upgrading of the common interest'. The outcome of the integration process will to some degree be dependent on its ability and will to perform this function. Thus 'cultivated spill-over' contitutes a voluntaristic element in an otherwise rather deterministic theory. *Summary and Predictions* Haas and Lindberg developed a theory of regional integration on the basis of studies of the early experiences of the European Community. Their main thesis was that sectoral integration was inherently expansive - integration of some functional tasks would tend to spill over into integration of other tasks. This logic was based on three distinct processes: functional, political and cultivated spill-over. On the basis of this analysis, Haas argued that an acceleration of the integration process could be 'safely predicted' and that it might lead to a 'political community of Europe' within a decade.31 Lindberg generally shared Haas's optimism, but cautiously added that '[t]here are a number of ways in which the processes of political integration might be interrupted'.32